Childhood Family Structure and Intergenerational Income Mobility in the United States

Abstract

The declining prevalence of two-parent families helped increment income inequality over recent decades. Does family structure also condition how economic (dis)advantages pass from parents to children? If so, shifts in the system of family unit life may contribute to enduring inequality between groups divers by childhood family structure. Using National Longitudinal Survey of Youth data, I combine parametric and nonparametric methods to reveal how family structure moderates intergenerational income mobility in the The states. I find that individuals raised outside stable two-parent homes are much more than mobile than individuals from stable two-parent families. Mobility increases with the number of family transitions but does not vary with children's time spent coresiding with both parents or stepparents provisional on a transition. Nonetheless, this mobility indicates insecurity, not opportunity. Difficulties maintaining middle-grade incomes create downwardly mobility among people raised outside stable two-parent homes. Regardless of parental income, these people are relatively probable to get low-income adults, reflecting a new form of perverse equality. People raised outside stable two-parent families are besides less likely to become high-income adults than people from stable two-parent homes. Mobility differences account for nearly 1-quarter of family unit-structure inequalities in income at the bottom of the income distribution and more than ane-third of these inequalities at the peak.

Notes

  1. Throughout this article, the term "both parents" denotes the ii parents with whom children resided at historic period 0 (overwhelmingly biological parents).

  2. A third theory holds that selection drives all mobility differences by childhood family unit construction. Particularly concerning are problematic traits or misfortunes generating low income amongst stable two-parent families (which are typically college income) or benign traits or circumstances generating high income among unstable or single-parent families (which are typically lower income). In the former case, negative option is expected to increase measured depression-income persistence amid children from stable two-parent families. In the latter case, positive pick is expected to increase measured loftier-income persistence among children from unstable or single-parent families. Following the tradition of mobility inquiry (described in the Data and Methods department), this article aims to provide reliable population descriptions of income persistence by childhood family structure. These descriptions illuminate the rigidity of inequality; future research could isolate the causal mechanisms generating this rigidity.

  3. My sample includes people whose childhoods span the early-1960s and early-1980s, a period of rapid family change. The share of children living with two parents dropped eleven pct points between 1960 and 1980; between 1980 and 2016, the share dropped 7.9 per centum points (U.S. Demography Bureau 2017).

  4. When respondents were young and many lived in their parents' households, parents provided income reports on a special survey version.

  5. Differential measurement error across family unit types is unlikely to bias my results, for three reasons. First, exclusion rates due to missing income (fewer than two observations per generation) were similar between stable two-parent and other families (differing by only 3 percentage points). In general, NLSY79 has remarkably high retentivity and low income nonresponse rates compared with other surveys (Pergamit et al. 2001). Biases from nonrandom compunction appear inconsequential (MaCurdy et al. 1998). 2d, the number of income reports contributed is also very similar across stable 2-parent and other families (averaging 3.3 vs. 3.4 years in childhood and 7.one vs. 7.v in adulthood). Third, mobility measures are less sensitive to measurement error than might exist expected (Gottschalk and Huynh 2010:311). Although classical measurement fault attenuates correlations toward 0 (indicating more than mobility in groups with more classical error), evidence shows that income measurement mistake is nonclassical. This nonclassical mistake often offsets attenuation biases in intertemporal correlations because errors correlate across time. These offsetting effects appear to extend beyond correlations/elasticities. Survey and administrative data produce similar earnings mobility estimates beyond several nonlinear measures (Dragoset and Fields 2008).

  6. Income from nonresidential family members, including noncustodial parents, is captured through kid support, alimony, and other "parental, relative support" every bit reported by the focal NLSY79 respondents' parents (during childhood) or the respondents themselves (during machismo). The survey design prevents researchers from observing other economical transfers from nonresident parents to NLSY79 respondents during childhood. The NLSY79 does capture biological parents' instruction, regardless of coresidence. Consequently, it is possible to study educational mobility relative to both resident and nonresident biological parents. Prior studies take addressed this topic (e.k., Kalmijn 2015). Thus, I study income mobility.

  7. I driblet nine individuals with nonpositive incomes.

  8. All family unit-construction measures capture coresidence but exercise not explicitly capture marital status. It is not possible to use the childhood residence calendar to split up coresidential relationships by marital status. All the same, this limitation is unlikely to be very problematic for this study because when the NLSY79 respondents were children (between the early-1960s and early-1980s), coresidential relationships between parents were very likely to be marital. It is also impossible to identify coresidence with "social parents" whom NLSY79 respondents did non call stepparents, adoptive parents, or foster parents in their childhood residence calendar responses. A terminal aspect of family complexity not captured by these data is the presence of half-siblings. This omission should not affect my conclusions because fifty-fifty in 2009, only 5.two % of children lived with two biological parents and a sibling who was not a full biological sibling (Manning et al. 2014).

  9. I include in the "stable, 2 parent" category 29 respondents who lived stably from ages 0 to xviii with two adoptive parents or i adoptive, i biological parent, and 11 respondents who lived stably from ages 0 to 18 with ane biological parent and i stepparent. Alternate codings leave my results unchanged.

  10. I too examined the number of years that respondents lived with both parents during different developmental stages, from ages 0–6, vii–12, and 13–18. I found no prove that living with both parents for different periods of fourth dimension matters differently for children's income mobility if this coresidence occurs during early, middle, or belatedly childhood.

  11. A few children are coded as experiencing nada transitions considering their residential situation is reported identically every twelvemonth from ages 0–eighteen, although their actual experience likely included transitions (e.m., children who reported living in foster care every twelvemonth, or with friends). Recoding these cases as experiencing one or two transitions leaves my results unchanged.

  12. Because incomes are logged in this approved representation of intergenerational mobility, β measures regression to the geometric mean of adult income, not the arithmetic mean (Mitnik et al. 2015). Like the median, the geometric mean of right-skewed variables like income lies below the arithmetic hateful. The geometric mean is more than resistant to outliers.

  13. I pool beyond genders (except when modeling earnings). I find no testify that family income persists differently for men and women within childhood family construction groups (see also Chadwick and Solon 2002; Mitnik et al. 2015).

  14. Without aligning, the intergenerational income elasticity is virtually .15 lower among children who did not grow upward in stable ii-parent families than among children who did (Table ane). Later adjustment using propensity score weighting, the divergence is slightly attenuated, to near .11 from .15. In the weighting approach, the stable 2-parent childhood family grouping is reweighted to capture the outcome that children from the alternative family unit group would have evidenced if they had (counter to fact) grown upwards in stable ii-parent families. With an appropriate weighting model, this approach identifies causal effects nether the (overly strong) assumption that provisional on the observed covariates, babyhood family structure "handling" is ignorable.

  15. I also used Bhattacharya and Mazumder's (2011) approach to report upward and downwardly rank mobility. Results confirmed the patterns evident from the multinomial and local polynomial models.

  16. This decomposition ignores differential fertility and mortality by parental income and childhood family construction. Previous analyses have found that the contributions of these differences to recent U.S. inequality trends are relatively pocket-size (Bloome 2014; Mare 1997).

  17. Children who lived with stepparents tended to feel more than transitions than children who did not. Models including 2-way and three-style interactions among parental income, babyhood family composition, and number of childhood family transitions cannot distinguish differences in mobility amid children who experienced two transitions but did versus did non live with stepparents.

  18. Signal estimates for ii versus three or more transitions are not statistically distinguishable in the nonlinear model. Yet, neither is the difference meaning between the guess for three transitions from the linear model and the estimate for iii or more transitions from the nonlinear model. The confidence interval for the nonlinear, three or more gauge is wider, reflecting data sparsity. Simply about six % of the sample experienced three or more transitions.

  19. Among people experiencing zero versus two babyhood family transitions, 51.ii % versus 37.7 % were stably married throughout adulthood. Income mobility differs by adult family unit structure even though income is family size–adjusted.

  20. Although the deviation in family income elasticities betwixt people experiencing zero versus 2 childhood family transitions is not statistically significant inside every gender-by-adult family construction group (Table 2, panel A), F tests reveal that interactions among log parental income, number of childhood family transitions, and adult family unit structure can be jointly statistically distinguished from zip but cannot exist distinguished from one some other. These tests indicate that childhood family unit transitions predict family income mobility fifty-fifty in models that condition on developed family structure and that there is bereft power to pinpoint how transitions predict mobility differently across adult family structures.

  21. These hypotheses might be tested using linked census data, which should capture both spouses' babyhood family structures, bold that married women can be linked to their parents despite surname changes.

  22. Researchers might disagree nigh when to measure childhood income relative to family transitions. Future studies might explore data that let investigations of income throughout childhood, including how mobility differs depending on the degree of homogamy among single/divorced parents who marry after a transition.

  23. Analyses of iii-manner interactions among parental income, childhood family structure, and race (supported past an oversample of African American respondents in the NLSY79) indicate that both not-Hispanic white and African American children experience higher intergenerational income mobility outside stable two-parent families than inside them. The mobility divergence is slightly, only not statistically significantly, larger amidst African Americans. Withal, because African American children are much less probable than white children to grow up in stable two-parent families, the family structure–mobility association is more consequential for perpetuating income inequality amongst African Americans than among whites at the population level. Information technology besides contributes to the persistence of racial inequalities in income (Bloome 2014).

  24. Aggregate income elasticities are non simple weighed averages of group-specific elasticities only also reflect income differences betwixt groups. Consequently, decreasing the weight on stable ii-parent elasticities could put downwardly force per unit area on the aggregate elasticity, just this change could be offset by changing income inequalities between family-structure groups or changing mobility patterns.

  25. U.South. income mobility appears trendless in recent decades (Chetty et al. 2014b; Lee and Solon 2009). Forces increasing and decreasing mobility may have counterbalanced one another (Bloome 2015).

References

  • Augustine, J. M. (2014). Maternal education and the unequal significance of family structure for children's early achievement. Social Forces, 83, 687–718.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Axinn, W. K., & Thornton, A. (1993). Mothers, children, and cohabitation: The intergenerational effects of attitudes and behavior. American Sociological Review, 58, 233–246.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Axinn, W. Thousand., & Thornton, A. (1996). The influence of parents' marital dissolutions on children's attitudes toward family formation. Demography, 33, 66–81.

    Commodity  Google Scholar

  • Baker, R. S. (2015). The irresolute association among marriage, work, and kid poverty in the United States, 1974–2010. Periodical of Union and Family, 77, 1166–1178.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Battle, J. (1997). The relative effects of married versus divorced family configuration and socioeconomic status on the educational accomplishment of African American center-class students. Journal of Negro Education, 66, 29–42.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Battle, J. (1998). What beats having two parents? Educational outcomes for African American students in single- versus dual-parent families. Journal of Blackness Studies, 28, 783–801.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Bhattacharya, D., & Mazumder, B. (2011). A nonparametric analysis of blackness-white differences in intergenerational income mobility in the Usa. Quantitative Economics, 3, 335–379.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Biblarz, T. J., & Raftery, A. East. (1993). The effects of family unit disruption on social mobility. American Sociological Review, 58, 97–109.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Biblarz, T. J., & Raftery, A. Due east. (1999). Family construction, educational attainment, and socioeconomic success: Rethinking the pathology of matriarchy. American Periodical of Sociology, 105, 321–365.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Biblarz, T. J., Raftery, A. E., & Bucur, A. (1997). Family structure and social mobility. Social Forces, 75, 1319–1339.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Björklund, A., & Chadwick, 50. (2003). Intergenerational income mobility in permanent and separated families. Economics Letters, 80, 239–246.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Blackness, South. Eastward., & Devereux, P. J. (2011). Recent developments in intergenerational mobility. In O. Ashenfelter & D. Card (Eds.), Handbook of labor economics (Vol. 4B, pp. 1487–1541). Amsterdam, The Netherlands: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar

  • Bloome, D. (2014). Racial inequality trends and the intergenerational persistence of income and family unit structure. American Sociological Review, 79, 1196–1225.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Bloome, D. (2015). Income inequality and intergenerational income mobility in the United states of america. Social Forces, 93, 1047–1080.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Brady, D., & Burroway, R. (2012). Targeting, universalism, and single-mother poverty: A multilevel assay beyond 18 affluent democracies. Demography, 49, 719–746.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Bratberg, East., Rieck, Yard. K. E., & Vaage, K. (2014). Intergenerational earnings mobility and divorce. Journal of Population Economic science, 27, 1107–1126.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Brown, S. 50. (2006). Family unit construction transitions and adolescent well-being. Demography, 43, 447–461.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Dark-brown, S. L. (2010). Marriage and child well-being: Research and policy perspectives. Journal of Marriage and Family, 72, 1059–1077.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Brown, S. 50., Stykes, J. B., & Manning, West. D. (2016). Trends in children's family instability, 1995–2010. Journal of Marriage and Family, 78, 1173–1183.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Burtless, Yard. (1999). Effects of growing wage disparities and irresolute family composition on the U.Due south. income distribution. European Economic Review, 43, 853–865.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Cancian, M., & Haskins, R. (2014). Changes in family limerick: Implications for income, poverty, and public policy. Register of the American University of Political and Social Science, 654, 31–47.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Chadwick, Fifty., & Solon, G. (2002). Intergenerational income mobility among daughters. American Economic Review, 92, 335–344.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Chetty, R., Hendren, Due north., Kline, P., & Saez, E. (2014a). Where is the land of opportunity? The geography of intergenerational mobility in the The states. Quarterly Periodical of Economics, 129, 1553–1623.

    Commodity  Google Scholar

  • Chetty, R., Hendren, Northward., Kline, P., Saez, East., & Turner, Due north. (2014b). Is the United States still a land of opportunity? Contempo trends in intergenerational mobility (NBER Working Paper No. 19844). Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Coleman, J. S. (1988). Social capital in the cosmos of human uppercase. American Journal of Sociology, 94, S95–S120.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Burrow, K. A., & Lillard, D. R. (1997). Divorce, educational attainment, and the earnings mobility of sons. Journal of Family and Economical Problems, 18, 231–245.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • DeLeire, T., & Lopoo, L. M. (2010). Family construction and the economical mobility of children (Economic Mobility Project report). Philadelpia, PA: Pew Charitable Trusts.

  • Dragoset, L. Chiliad., & Fields, K. Southward. (2008). U.Due south. earnings mobility: Comparing survey-based and administrative-based estimates (ILR working paper). Ithaca, NY: Cornell University.

  • Fomby, P., & Cherlin, A. J. (2007). Family instability and kid wellbeing. American Sociological Review, 72, 181–204.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Fomby, P., & Osborne, C. (2010). The influence of union instability and union quality on children's aggressive behavior. Social Scientific discipline Enquiry, 39, 912–924.

    Commodity  Google Scholar

  • Furstenberg, F. F. (2014). 50 years of family change: From consensus to complexity. Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 654, 12–30.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Gelman, A., Carlin, J. B., Stern, H. S., & Rubin, D. B. (2004). Bayesian data analysis (2nd ed.). Boca Raton, FL: Chapman and Hall/CRC Press.

  • Gottschalk, P., & Huynh, M. (2010). Are earnings inequality and mobility overstated? The touch on of nonclassical measurement error. Review of Economics and Statistics, 92, 302–315.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Grusky, D. B., & Cumberworth, E. (2010, February). A national protocol for measuring intergenerational mobility? Newspaper presented at the National University of Science Workshop on Advancing Social Science Theory: The Importance of Mutual Metrics, Washington, DC.

  • Haider, Southward., & Solon, 1000. (2006). Life-cycle variation in the association between electric current and lifetime earnings. American Economic Review, 96, 1308–1320.

    Commodity  Google Scholar

  • Hofferth, Southward. L., & Anderson, M. G. (2003). Are all dads equal? Biological science versus marriage every bit a basis for paternal investment. Journal of Matrimony and Family unit, 65, 213–232.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Hogan, D. P., & Featherman, D. L. (1977). Racial stratification and socioeconomic change in the American North and S. American Journal of Folklore, 83, 100–126.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Hout, Thousand. (2004). How inequality may affect intergenerational mobility. In K. Chiliad. Neckerman (Ed.), Social inequality (pp. 969–984). New York, NY: Russell Sage.

    Google Scholar

  • Jäntti, M., & Jenkins, S. (2013). Income mobility (SOEP Papers on Multidisciplinary Panel Data Research, No. 607). Berlin, Germany: German language Socio-Economic Panel.

    Google Scholar

  • Jodl, Chiliad. G., Michael, A., Malanchuk, O., Eccles, J. S., & Sameroff, A. (2001). Parents' roles in shaping early adolescents' occupational aspirations. Child Development, 72, 1247–1265.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Jones, J., & Mosher, W. D. (2013). Fathers' involvement with their children: U.s., 2006–2010 (National Wellness Statistics Reports, No. 71). Hyattsville, MD: National Center for Health Statistics.

  • Kalil, A., Ryan, R., & Chor, Eastward. (2014). Time investments in children across family structures. Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 654, 150–168.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Kalmijn, 1000. (2015). Family disruption and intergenerational reproduction: Comparing the influences of married parents, divorced parents, and stepparents. Demography, 52, 811–833.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Kennedy, S., & Bumpass, L. L. (2008). Cohabitation and children's living arrangements: New estimates from the U.s.a.. Demographic Research, 19(article 47), 1663–1692. doi:ten.4054/DemRes.2008.xix.47

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Kitagawa, E. M. (1955). Components of a difference betwixt two rates. Periodical of the American Statistical Association, 50, 1168–1194.

    Google Scholar

  • Lee, C.-I., & Solon, G. (2009). Trends in intergenerational income mobility. Review of Economic science and Statistics, 91, 766–772.

  • Lee, D., & McLanahan, S. (2015). Family structure transitions and child development: Instability, selection, and population heterogeneity. American Sociological Review, 80, 738–763.

    Commodity  Google Scholar

  • Li, J.-C. A., & Wu, L. L. (2008). No trend in the intergenerational manual of divorce. Demography, 45, 875–883.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Lopoo, L. Thou., & DeLeire, T. (2014). Family construction and the economic wellbeing of children in youth and adulthood. Social Science Research, 43, 30–44.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • MaCurdy, T., Mroz, T., & Gritz, R. Chiliad. (1998). An evaluation of the National Longitudinal Survey on Youth. Periodical of Homo Resource, 33, 345–436.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Magnuson, K., & Berger, Fifty. One thousand. (2009). Family structure states and transitions: Associations with children's well-being during eye childhood. Journal of Matrimony and Family, 71, 575–591.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Manning, W. D., Brown, S. L., & Stykes, J. B. (2014). Family complexity amid children in the The states. Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 654, 48–65.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Mare, R. D. (1996). Demography and the evolution of educational inequality. In J. N. Baron, D. B. Grusky, & D. J. Treiman (Eds.), Social differentiation and social inequality: Theoretical and empirical inquiries. Essays in honor of John C. Pock (pp. 117–162). Boulder, CO: Westview Press.

  • Mare, R. D. (1997). Differential fertility, intergenerational educational mobility, and racial inequality. Social Science Inquiry, 26, 263–291.

    Commodity  Google Scholar

  • Mare, R. D. (2011). A multigenerational view of inequality. Demography, 48, 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Martin, 1000. A. (2006). Family structure and income inequality in families with children: 1976–2000. Demography, 43, 421–445.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Martin, Grand. A. (2012). Family structure and the intergenerational manual of educational advantage. Social Science Research, 41, 33–47.

    Commodity  Google Scholar

  • Mayer, S. Due east. (1997). What money can't buy: Family income and children's life chances. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

  • Mazumder, B. (2005). Fortunate sons: New estimates of intergenerational mobility in the United States using Social Security earnings information. Review of Economics and Statistics, 87, 235–255.

    Commodity  Google Scholar

  • Mazumder, B. (2014). Black-white differences in intergenerational economic mobility in the United States (Economical Perspectives Report No. 1Q). Chicago, IL: Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.

  • McLanahan, S. (2004). Diverging destinies: How children fare nether the second demographic transition. Demography, 41, 607–627.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • McLanahan, Due south., & Sandefur, Thousand. D. (1994). Growing upwardly with a single parent: What hurts, what helps? Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Printing.

  • McLanahan, South., Tach, L., & Schneider, D. (2013). The causal effects of father absence. Almanac Review of Sociology, 39, 399–427.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Mitchell, C., McLanahan, S., Hobcraft, J., Brooks-Gunn, J., Garfinkel, I., & Notterman, D. (2015). Family construction instability, genetic sensitivity, and child well-being. American Periodical of Folklore, 120, 1195–1225.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Mitnik, P. A., Bryant, V., Weber, M., & Grusky, D. B. (2015). New estimates of intergenerational mobility using administrative data (Statistics of Income Division working newspaper). Washington, DC: Internal Acquirement Service.

    Google Scholar

  • Musick, Grand., & Mare, R. D. (2006). Recent trends in the inheritance of poverty and family construction. Social Science Enquiry, 35, 471–499.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Pergamit, G. R., Pierret, C. R., Rothstein, D. S., & Veum, J. R. (2001). Data watch: The National Longitudinal Surveys. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15(2), 239–253.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Peters, H. East. (1992). Patterns of intergenerational mobility in income and earnings. Review of Economic science and Statistics, 74, 456–466.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Ribar, D. C. (2015). Why marriage matters for child wellbeing. Future of Children, 25(2), 11–27.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Seltzer, J. A. (1994). Consequences of marital dissolution for children. Annual Review of Sociology, 20, 235–266.

    Commodity  Google Scholar

  • Solon, G. (1999). Intergenerational mobility in the labor market. In O. Ashenfelter & D. Carte (Eds.), Handbook of labor economics (Vol. 3, pp. 1761–1800). Amsterdam, The netherlands: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar

  • Tach, L. One thousand. (2015). Social mobility in an era of family unit instability and complication. Annals of the American University of Political and Social Science, 657, 83–96.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Tach, L. G., & Eads, A. (2015). Trends in the economic consequences of marital and cohabitation dissolution in the Us. Demography, 52, 401–432.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Teachman, J. D., Paasch, M., & Carver, K. (1996). Social capital and dropping out of school early on. Periodical of Marriage and Family, 58, 773–783.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Teachman, J. D., Paasch, One thousand., & Carver, Thousand. (1997). Social capital and the generation of human majuscule. Social Forces, 575, 1343–1359.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Thornton, A., Axinn, West. G., & Xie, Y. (2007). Marriage and cohabitation. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

  • U.S. Census Bureau. (2017). Living arrangements of children under 18 years former: 1960 to present (Table CH-1). Retrieved from http://www.census.gov/hhes/families/data/children.html

  • Western, B., Bloome, D., & Percheski, C. (2008). Inequality among American families with children, 1975–2005. American Sociological Review, 73, 903–920.

    Commodity  Google Scholar

  • Wu, 50. L. (1996). Effects of family instability, income, and income instability on the hazard of a premarital birth. American Sociological Review, 61, 386–406.

    Article  Google Scholar

  • Wu, L. L., & Martinson, B. C. (1993). Family structure and the risk of a premarital nativity. American Sociological Review, 58, 210–232.

    Article  Google Scholar

Download references

Acknowledgments

This article has benefitted from the useful comments of Census editors and reviewers, Paula Fomby, Christopher Jencks, Karen Lacy, Laura Tach, Bruce Western, William Julius Wilson, Lawrence Wu, and seminar participants at Columbia University and the Academy of Pennsylvania. This inquiry was supported by a Ford Fund grant from the Population Studies Center at the University of Michigan and an NICHD center grant to the Population Studies Heart at the University of Michigan (R24 HD041028).

Author information

Affiliations

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Deirdre Bloome.

About this article

Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bloome, D. Childhood Family Structure and Intergenerational Income Mobility in the United States. Demography 54, 541–569 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s13524-017-0564-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Engagement:

  • DOI : https://doi.org/10.1007/s13524-017-0564-4

Keywords

  • Intergenerational mobility
  • Family structure
  • Family dynamics
  • Income inequality

comeausirsenes.blogspot.com

Source: https://link.springer.com/article/10.1007/s13524-017-0564-4

0 Response to "Childhood Family Structure and Intergenerational Income Mobility in the United States"

Post a Comment

Iklan Atas Artikel

Iklan Tengah Artikel 1

Iklan Tengah Artikel 2

Iklan Bawah Artikel